West African farming does really well
internationally only with crops
where its hot, humid climate gives it an overwhelming advantage, cocoa
being the prime example. Cocoa accounts for over 50% of West
Africa's agricultural exports (FAO, Agricultural
Growth...p.
105), but even in this sector, the region faces rising challenges from
a few other areas of the world with similar climate, such as Indonesia.
Without cocoa the
West African agricultural picture would be even bleaker. In rice,
a vital West African food,
the yield was 2009 kg/ha for the period 2008-2012. In Sub-Saharan
Africa as a whole the figure was 2,523, in South-Eastern Asia 4,136
kg/ha. For oil palm the West African yield was 3,261 kg/ha, Sub-Saharan
Africa 3,863 and South-East Asia 18,868 kg/ha (all figures FAO, p. 76).
Why does West Africa,
despite its apparent advantages, perform so poorly in agriculture
relative to the rest of the world? Surely many of the problems listed
above by the FAO are shared or were shared at the outset (Independence)
with
many other countries around the world. How did they rise above the
problems whilst West Africa has been unable to? And why is the
situation more or less the same in all
countries of the region? Could there be a common factor driving the
lethargy?
Again and again, I am drawn to the issue of land tenure. West
African agricultural lands are overwhelmingly held under customary,
communal land tenure. Unlike East and Southern Africa, plantation
agriculture never took strong hold in West Africa. West African lands
are
generally not bought or sold and
are not subject to market forces. They are held without formal
title by communities and families, usually under the overall direction
of traditional chiefs. Individual ownership in perpetuity is for the
most part forbidden. In practice, capital investment on these farms is
extremely limited. This was perhaps acceptable when these were small,
isolated communities more or less cut off from the rest of the world.
In today's world, these agricultural producers face direct competition
from the international market. International rice, Thai, Burmese,
Vietnamese, Indian, what have you, floods West African markets and even
West African villages. Why enter battle
against the might of the international free market with one hand tied
behind the back? Why exclude
one of your most formidable weapons (capital) in a contest against the
rest of
the world?
Maintaining two economic systems within a single national entity, as
all West African nations do, is
fraught with difficulty. There is almost inevitably a steady,
debilitating flight of people and capital from one to the other. In the
West African setting, the movement is of course away from the communal
land tenure of the
countryside and towards the freehold system of the cities. Ivory
Coast is the exception that proves the rule. Of all West Africans the
Ivorians are unquestionably the top agricultural nation. Ivory Coast
is, by a large margin, the world's top cocoa producer and exporter. Due
to its huge cocoa exports Ivory Coast enjoys a large agricultural trade
balance with the rest of the world. The country is also West Africa's
leading exporter of coffee, palm oil, rubber, cashew nuts and bananas
(FAO, Agricultural Growth...,
p. 105). However, the Ivorian miracle is not all it seems. The
country's large agricultural exports were stimulated by official
government encouragement for farmers in the north of the country
and beyond to move into the more fertile south. But the position of
these "strangers" was always somewhat vulnerable within customary land
systems and made even more so by a 1998 law introduced by
then-President Bedié that strengthened the hand of the locals,
some of whom returned from the cities to reclaim "their" lands. The
large migrant community in the Ivory Coast, some citizens, some not,
without clear title to land under the traditional land tenure system,
became a factor in the country's ensuing conflicts (Land, Agricultural
Change and Conflict in West Africa. Regional Issues from Sierra Leone,
Liberia and Cote d'Ivoire). For all its agricultural
success,
Ivory
Coast is in the bottom 25 of the UN's HDI. Much of its agriculture
suffers from the same problem of low productivity as the rest of West
Africa (FAO, Agricultural Growth...,table
3-5). Its exports are built on mobilising large
numbers of farm workers on large amounts of land rather than on
improving land productivity (output per hectare) and labour
productivity
(output per farmer).
The dinosaur of African communalism
refuses to die even as its distant, vastly more formidable
cousin, communism, has retreated almost into obscurity in the face of
capitalism's march. Socio-economic systems developed for small,
isolated tribal units deep within West Africa's rain forests still hold
sway in a modern, highly interconected era that thrives on freedom of
movement, of information, of capital, of goods. These are the vitals
that oil economies all round the rest of the world, the antithesis of
the closed societal culture from which West Africa's traditions of
lineage, "strangers" and tutorat
have emerged. Of
course the
traditional West African systems are grossly uncompetitive.
These traditional systems are protected by a fierce lobby within West
Africa and without. First and foremost the rural elite, the chiefs and
the heads of families, clans and communities, who benefit greatly from
control of this most important resource. Secondly, in many instances,
the political elite in the capitals, who have ultimate control over the
rural elite. And thirdly, the worldwide liberal movement, which
ideologically believes all socio-cultural systems are equal and is
opposed to any policy that smacks of imposition of "Western" values.
This liberal lobby is well represented in powerful global institutions
like the UN and its agencies, the World Bank and IMF, the ADB and other
multilateral and bilateral aid organizations.
Land reform has been on the fringes of the political agenda for many
years in West Africa. I research the subject and find The Sahel Club's
2006 paper, Land
Reform Processes in West Africa, A Review. It
provides a brief history of land law in all fifteen countries of ECOWAS
plus Cameroon, Chad and Mauritania and a summary of the efforts then
being undertaken at reform. It reveals an intractable, complex and
diverse customary land tenure regime throughout the region, fiercely
resistant to change for decades. People have been highlighting this
problem for the last forty or fifty years. It's an impossible
situation. In Sierra Leone, private property was introduced to Freetown
by the Settlers in the 1780s. A few decades later the same thing
happened in Liberia. Even though the forms of government in the two
countries were diametrically opposite, one a Settler government, the
other a colonial one, the end result in so far as the land regimes were
concerned was identical: an enclave of private property surrounded by
huge swathes of communally-held countryside. Introduction of
plantations in Ivory Coast, Guinea and elsewhere by the French again
failed to
budge the traditional systems.
Freehold title encourages investment, both private and commercial. The
miracle of compounding means that over the fifty or sixty odd years
since Independence, even tiny amounts of yearly investment add up to
large productivity enhancing improvements on the land. The invisible
hand of capitalism triumphs. If Pa Chan, in Thailand, and Pa Kofi in
Ghana operated equally capitalized farms in 1957, when Ghana attained
Independence, and if Pa Chan was able to achieve an annual investment
rate just one percent greater than Pa Kofi because of the attractions
of his freehold ownership, today sixty years later, Pa Chan's
descendants would be blessed with a considerably larger and more
productive farm than would Pa Kofi's. Within the freehold system, the
investments of thousands and thousands
of individual farmers, the built-up capital, are handed down securely
to their trusted designees, usually their children, to be built
upon and amplified, rather than disappearing within the communal system
into the no-man's land of
the extended family or the community, where every individual wonders
who might be the eventual beneficiary of his contemplated investment.
If the enormities of a huge agricultural deficit and world-trailing
human development were not enough, West Africa faces other, major
challenges, including political, ethnic, religious and separatist
tensions, declining patriotism evidenced by a growing migration, legal
and illegal, to the West, and the rise of Boku Haram and militant
Islam. There are differences between the different countries of course,
but for the region as a whole, these problems are getting worse, not
better. Does all this mean West African states are in danger of
imminent
collapse. Maybe, maybe not. But after fifty to sixty years of
Independence will they all survive in their present form another fifty
or sixty years? Probably not. Independence brought hope of a better
life. That hope cemented the union of disparate tribes, religions
and cultures into bright young nations. After two generations, in many
West African countries, that
hope is almost dead.